Interesting People mailing list archives

How Workarounds Drive Telecom and Networking


From: David Farber <dave () farber net>
Date: Sat, 2 May 2009 19:29:17 -0400



Begin forwarded message:

From: dewayne () warpspeed com (Dewayne Hendricks)
Date: May 1, 2009 11:26:26 PM EDT
To: Dewayne-Net Technology List <xyzzy () warpspeed com>
Subject: [Dewayne-Net] How Workarounds Drive Telecom and Networking

April 29, 2009

How Workarounds Drive Telecom and Networking
By Fred Goldstein
ionary Consulting
<http://ipcommunications.tmcnet.com/topics/ip-communications/articles/55155-how-workarounds-drive-telecom-networking.htm >

We like to think that the course of progress is dictated by scientific discovery, and by the work done by technologists and engineers to put it to practical use. But the dirty little secret of the telecommunications and networking industry is that it’s driven less by technical reality and more by a drive to work around regulatory absurdities. We have become so accustomed to this way of doing business that we don’t even notice what should be obvious! This is particularly true for the United States, but as the world’s largest market, it sets much of the direction for everyone else.

Pretty much everything in the Internet sector owes its existence to some foolish rule or another, either directly or indirectly. The most telling case is the status of the Internet itself, as well as the status of “IP-enabled services” such as Voice over IP (VoIP). Put it next to the telecom industry, the historically-regulated common carriers, and see how the two deal with each other, and the ironies become clear.

Telecom Was A Fantasy World Of Monopoly
For most of its life, the telecom industry was simply the telephone industry, primarily offering voice service across a ubiquitous, regulated network. When Bell’s patents expired in 1893, the industry became very competitive. Eventually, AT&T managed to create a system of territorial exclusivity, and by the time the Communication Act of 1934 was passed, there was no competition left. So the regulations of the day locked in the monopoly.

Once competition is prohibited, prices can more easily deviate wildly from costs. Regulators liked the monopoly because it let them constrain the price of basic residential local service. “Residual pricing” was one such regulatory scheme, to maximize monopoly profits wherever possible so that the basic residential rate only had to cover the residue, not all of its own costs. State regulators were even adopting residual pricing plans into the 1990s. No wonder so many opposed every move to open up competition, from Carterfone (which allowed customers to attach their own equipment to telephone lines, rather than just rent from the phone company) to long distance and then local competition. And many tradition-minded regulators were uncomfortable with the Internet itself, which lived in a free-market cocoon of its own.

Vertical Integration Bound Facilities To Services
Another part of telecom policy was the coupling of physical facilities to the services that used them. Telephone wires were owned by the service provider, and were only designed, or upgraded, as that service provider saw fit. This vertical integration was not an issue when the one service that really mattered was Plain Old Telephone Service. In that era, the main issue was balancing the price of calls vs. the price of the line itself. Only a small portion of the actual cost of telephone service is usage sensitive. Long distance calls, and in some places local calls, were priced far above cost, in order to subsidize the fixed price of local service and pay for the expensive wires up on the poles and under the streets.

This service-driven model quietly started to fall apart in the 1980s when fiber optics became practical. Fiber changed the key economics. Up until then, high-capacity services were very expensive to provision, so they had to be expensive. Even a measly copper T1 circuit, 1.5 megabits, leased for thousands per month. A strand of fiber was far more versatile, and had enough capacity to “bypass” many billable phone calls. Fiber could have been seen as infrastructure, but that was not compatible with a service-driven business model.

Crippling The Promise Of Fiber
One group of telco people, the engineers, got together in the 1980s to figure out how to light up the fiber that they assumed would be brought to most homes by end of the century. The ITU standards committees came up with a concept called Broadband ISDN, and developed a core technology for it called ATM. But the engineers had no say in how to charge for it. That was someone else’s problem, and those suits turned out to not have a good answer at all. If high-bandwidth services could be priced at a level that would stimulate demand, then existing low-bandwidth cash cow services might lose revenues to them, a process known as cannibalization.

I know the irony well: I was on a B-ISDN standards committee, representing Digital Equipment Corp., at the time a computer industry giant. They too worried about cannibalization. In the 1980s, their VAX minicomputer line was very profitable, but then cheap commodity PCs became available. Digital didn’t want to cannibalize high-margin VAX sales with low-margin PCs, so they avoided the PC business. Of course this didn’t stop others from killing their high-margin business. If you don’t cannibalize yourself, somebody else will. And Digital’s estate is now owned (via Compaq) by one of its former competitors, Hewlett-Packard, who learned to deal with the new realities rather than deny them.

[snip]RSS Feed: <http://www.warpspeed.com/wordpress>




-------------------------------------------
Archives: https://www.listbox.com/member/archive/247/=now
RSS Feed: https://www.listbox.com/member/archive/rss/247/
Powered by Listbox: http://www.listbox.com


Current thread: