Politech mailing list archives

FC: ICANN problems still fester at the core --Milton Mueller


From: Declan McCullagh <declan () well com>
Date: Wed, 12 Jan 2000 09:55:41 -0500

*********

[Milton is an ICANN critic who has written on the topic for Cato before. I will forward any responses (if there are any) from ICANN reps. As a side note I had promised to do the same re: the OSHA regs last week but my subsequent silence was due to my inability to find someone willing to defend them, not lack of interest in an opposing view. John Young wrote in but he was defending OSHA in general and not their latest action. --Declan]

*********

11 January 2000
NEWS RELEASE
Fundamental untruth festers at ICANN's core

ICANN's creation and the ensuing internet domain name war has delayed
the introduction of new top-level domains that can compete with NSI's
dot com, says internet analyst, Milton Mueller.

In an article just published in info, the journal of policy, regulation
and strategy for telecommunications, information and media, Mueller
provides an independent and comprehensive assessment of the first year
of existence of The Internet Corporation for Assigned Names and Numbers.

Mueller evaluates the policy of private sector 'self-regulation' of
internet names and numbers. He concludes that  'self-regulation' was not
a coherent policy but a rhetorical device used by the Internet Society
in a power struggle with Network Solutions Inc to legitimate and
preserve its own control.

Mueller is highly critical of the US government in allowing the Internet
Society to install ICANN's initial board. In doing so, the US government
undermined ICANN's capacity for consensus building.

Ironically, owing to the bitter controversies surrounding it, ICANN has
not avoided government regulation since the US Commerce Department
intends to retain 'policy authority' over the DNS root indefinitely and
has imposed utility-style regulation upon Network Solutions' wholesale
prices.

According to Mueller, "…the 'self-regulatory regime' being constructed
by ICANN is actually far more centralized and controlling in nature then
the pre-ICANN internet. Is it all that different from what could have
been expected of direct government intervention?"

Mueller believes that "a fundamental untruth" festers at ICANN's core.
"Official US policy characterized the creation of ICANN as a private-
sector driven process that did not affect basic political and legal
rights. It described an act of imposing wholesale centralization and
regulation at the internet's core as a way to avoid 'government
regulation'. The rhetoric of market liberalism was cynically abused to
gloss over the true nature of the transition. The tumult of ICANN's
first year is the price being paid for that."

...

For the complete article:
Colin Blackman, info
Tel: +44 1223 509161
Email: crblackman () camford demon co uk

***********

Date: Tue, 11 Jan 2000 13:11:55 -0500
From: Milton Mueller <mueller () syr edu>
To: Declan McCullagh <declan () well com>

Here's a big "excerpt" which you can put on politech if it's not too big:
It's the concluding section.
------------
“Self-regulation” in perspective
It is useless to debate concepts such as “private sector leadership,” “avoiding government intervention,” or “self-governance” in the abstract. To understand what these abstractions really mean, one must examine the historical process through
which ICANN came into being. That analysis makes it clear that the policy is
flawed both in its conception and its implementation.
Conception
Self-regulation of Internet names and numbers is not at all comparable to the
other areas where the concept has been applied. Content labeling standards and
privacy codes of conduct, for example, both involve collective action by
well-established industries around narrowly circumscribed areas of conduct. The
basic institutional regime under which these businesses operate predate the
“self-regulation” process and are fairly clear and stable.
Internet governance, on the other hand, involved creating an entirely new
institutional and property rights framework. At its center was the problem of who owned critically important, valuable assets: the name and address spaces. Control
of these assets had to be transferred from an informal set of relationships
loosely centered in the US government and its private contractors to a formal,
internationally representative, legally incorporated entity. A host of related and very complicated property rights issues flowed from that. How could domain name registration, which provided globally exclusive control of a character string, be reconciled with trademark protection, which provided jurisdiction-, industry-, and product-specific forms of protection to certain names? What rules or procedures
governed access to the root of the domain name space? How much control did a
domain name registry have over the zone files containing the authoritative list of second-level names? These and many other difficult questions were fundamentally
legal in nature; that is, the way in which they were decided assigned property
rights to specific actors and strengthened or diminished various individuals’
freedom of action. The legal questions were greatly complicated by the global,
trans-jurisdictional scope of the system. The Commerce Department basically
devolved global state power to ICANN.
To call such a policy a form of “self-regulation” comparable to the voluntary
adoption of a code of conduct by an established group of businesses is not just mistaken, but dangerously obtuse. The error was compounded by the fact that the
private sector itself was deeply, bitterly divided over the resolution of the
property rights questions. The divisions were neither irrational nor minor.
Control of valuable assets was up for grabs. Decisions about the distribution of property rights and transaction costs would create major winners and losers. There was little incentive for the contesting parties to cooperate or compromise. On the contrary, the situation gave private and public sector actors powerful incentives
to seize control of the process or to win a struggle for power. There was a
pressing need for an impartial government to impose constraints upon the process
based on some notion of justice and the proper distribution of rights.
Under these circumstances, the Clinton administration’s decision to throw up its
hands and wait for the “Internet community” to come forward with a “consensus
proposal” was disingenuous, at best. It is clear from the detailed history
presented above that “private sector leadership” did not mean turning over
governance to the Internet industry and its users to work out for themselves—even
if that had been possible. In practice, “self-regulation” was a code word for
something very different:
a) leaving control of name and address administration in the hands of the
hierarchy established by the Internet Society and a small band of its corporate
allies, and
b) implementing a private deal made between a few government officials in the US
Commerce Department and the EC.
The real object of “self-regulation” seems to have been avoidance of any formal,
public processes.
Implementation
If the results of the policy are good, criticisms of the conceptual basis for the
policy are rendered irrelevant. The white paper’s impact can be benchmarked
against its own professed criteria:
* Fostering stability
* Encouragement of stakeholder consensus
* Creating competition in the domain name markets
* Resolving domain name-trademark conflicts
* Avoiding government intrusion
Stability
Preserving the “stability” of the Internet is frequently cited as the “first
principle” of the Commerce Department and its corporate backers. The idea that
computer internetworking and e-commerce could flourish without the direct
involvement of a centralized, government-sanctioned authority is completely alien
to them. Leaving aside the question whether that assumption is true, recent
developments have shown that the US government’s concern about “stability” is
fundamentally at odds with its nominal commitment to “private sector
self-regulation.” The government has been forced to state explicitly that it is unwilling to relinquish policy authority over the root because of the instability engendered by its own process. It was unwilling to stand aside and let ICANN and
NSI and other private sector players work out their differences on their own.
Indeed, it seems evident now that the biggest threat to stability came from the government’s logically inconsistent form of intervention. If the government wanted to regulate and subordinate NSI, it should have done so directly and openly, via laws and regulations. Instead, it created a private sector corporation that was
completely dominated by avowed enemies of NSI, and then expected NSI to
voluntarily play along. The resulting blood feud was predictable. And just as
predictably, in the end all the real work was performed by the US government, not by ICANN. It was the Commerce Department that regulated NSI’s rates and practices and renegotiated its contract in ways that got it to recognize ICANN and find a place within its regime. ICANN simply had no leverage other than as a proxy for the Commerce Department. One could therefore reasonably ask, what purpose did the
philosophy of “self-regulation” serve?
The threats to stability are not over. ICANN is now a heavily politicized
organization that is attracting the interest and attention of the
politically-minded. There will be more power struggles, more polarization as this
process continues.
Stakeholder consensus
The Commerce Department allowed ICANN’s initial board to be selected in secret by
a group with a divisive policy agenda. The determination of that faction to
implement its policies as quickly as possible seriously undermined the new
corporation’s ability to function as a vehicle for consensual policy development.
As the conflicting forces met on the battleground known as ICANN, its
organizational units metastasized into a structure of byzantine complexity, and
its processes took on the character of sheer adhocracy.
We can say without qualification that ICANN has failed to provide a vehicle for
developing “stakeholder consensus.” ICANN’s creation has not resolved the DNS
wars; it has simply fostered a political competition that allowed one faction to win at the expense of others. And it is a serious mistake to view the dissent as a
product of NSI’s opposition alone. Virtually every major academic who follows
ICANN is positioned on the critical side of the spectrum; opposition to ICANN has
united Naderites and libertarians.
Competition in the domain name space
Two and a half years after the initiation of the NTIA process, there are still no new gTLD registries authorized to compete with Network Solutions’ dot com. In its responses to Congressional inquiries, the Department of Commerce has complained repeatedly of the enormous market power of NSI and the complex problems it poses.
But the Commerce Dept itself is responsible for that market dominance. In 1997
NSI, in response to requests by competing registries, asked whether it could add new TLDs to the DNS root. The National Science Foundation was prepared to let it do so, but the Commerce Department prevented it. The object of this refusal was to protect trademark holders and, more subtly and importantly, to avoid creating new
stakeholders in the root that might undermine Commerce’s ability to impose a
centralized policy on the process. During the White Paper process the Commerce
Department originally came up with a detailed proposal for quickly adding five new gTLDs to the root, but then bowed to pressure from foreign governments and ISOC to
leave that decision to the new corporation.
Those delays have been a devastating setback to the cause of competition in DNS. Commerce has delayed competition for more than two years. During that period the number of .com, .net, and .org domain name registrations quadrupled and the .com TLD obtained an almost unbreakable hold on the minds of Internet businesses as the place to be visible. Although ICANN is now established as the authority for adding
new TLDs, its procedures for doing so are multi-layered bureaucratic processes
dominated by established stakeholders, such as trademark holders, country code TLD
registries, and large businesses with an established stake in dot com. Many of
these players have a vested interest in preventing the addition of new registries
and new gTLDs.
ICANN’s formation was followed by the opening up of the .com, .net, and .org
domains to registrar competition. But there is less here than meets the eye. The registry is still a monopoly, it is just being regulated. The transformation of the NSI gTLDs into a regulated, shared system is a product of direct government
intervention by the US Dept of Commerce, not the work of ICANN. It was the
Commerce Dept’s contractual agreement with NSI that created the shared
registration system and imposed wholesale price regulation on NSI. ICANN and its
processes were completely unnecessary to the achievement of that goal. And the
benefits of registrar competition are not all that impressive.
Trademark-domain name conflicts.
ICANN has provided the institutional mechanism for the development of a global,
uniform process to resolve disputes between trademark holders and domain name
registrants. Indeed, ICANN and WIPO together have given trademark and intellectual property interests a privileged role in the definition of a new system of global administrative law. Without ICANN’s grip on access to the root of the domain name
system and its ability to leverage that monopoly into a system of centralized,
uniform contracts, it would be impossible to impose uniformity on the process. But
even here, there are strong reasons to doubt whether ICANN was needed. Despite
ICANN’s existence, trademark lobbyists have prevailed upon the US Congress to pass powerful new laws that punish “cybersquatters” and extend trademark protections
into the assignment of domain names. Trademark owners are now complaining that
ICANN’s dispute resolution process is too fair to domain name holders and they
will not use it. Countries such as New Zealand, in contrast, have succeeded in
completely separating trademark disputes from domain name registrations, leaving resolution to the courts. After court precedents in New Zealand made it clear that cybersquatting was illegal, there does not seem to be any significant problem in
that country.
Avoidance of governmental intrusion
Keeping things out of the hands of “government” has been one of the leitmotifs of ISOC and its supporters. But what is the object of this avoidance? To prevent name
and number administration from falling into the hands of a top-heavy, ITU-like
intergovernmental organization? To prevent burdensome regulation of the Internet
and its content? Certainly, the public comments in the Commerce Department
proceedings and IFWP processes document overwhelming support for the principle of a lightweight ICANN strictly confined to technical coordination of the Internet. But ICANN has completely failed to live up to that promise. Even before ICANN’s creation, the Internet Society’s Faustian bargains with the ITU and the trademark
interests, coupled with the Clinton administration’s subservience to trademark
lobby demands, had already undermined the neutrality of name and address
administration. Linking trademark protection to DNS administration completely
politicized the process of domain name assignment. Once it became evident that
domain name administration could be leveraged into a mechanism for policing and enforcing property rights in names, ICANN became a de facto legislator, a definer and enforcer of rights. These functions encroached deeply into the territory of governmental power. It was only natural, then, for ICANN to be subject to the same demands for accountability and procedure as a governmental body. Those demands in
turn are leading inexorably to the growth of bureaucracy and formal procedure.
(Prediction: if ICANN survives another five years, it will rival the ITU in size.)
Had the Clinton administration’s white paper explicitly and firmly distanced
Internet administration from trademark protection and other issues not directly related to technical coordination of the Internet, then its policy of “industry self-regulation” would have had some coherence. But the White Paper was first and
foremost a political bargain; its commitment to self-regulation and private
enterprise was mainly rhetorical.
The same tendency to stray into the realm of regulation and governance is evident
in the new regime’s approach to the creation of competition in domain name
registration. ISOC’s gTLD-MoU and its deep-seated animosity to NSI committed it to
a specific business model for domain name registries. The gTLD-MoU adherents
profess an ideological, almost religious belief that all domain name registries must be non-profit and permit shared access to TLDs for competing registrars on
equal terms. Whether one supports or opposes that agenda, the imposition of a
specific economic model on private sector businesses is a regulatory function. In
order to enforce this model upon registrants, ICANN has had to establish a
contract-based accreditation system that is highly centralized and regulatory. The US Commerce Dept, likewise, has imposed a cost-plus utility regulation model upon NSI via its cooperative agreement contract. This is not technical coordination but
economic regulation.
Finally, ICANN has failed to avoid an even more direct form of government
involvement: the sovereignty claims on country code TLDs advanced by national
governments. Governments were given a direct channel in ICANN via its Government Advisory Commission (GAC), and the GAC has been used as the point of departure for
declaring the name space a “public resource.”

The new regime is establishing sweeping new rights for trademark and intellectual
property holders. It is asserting forms of economic control over domain name
registries and registrars that did not exist before. It has provided a vehicle
through which national governments can assert sovereignty claims over the name
space. In short, the “self-regulatory regime” being constructed by ICANN is
actually far more centralized and controlling in nature than the pre-ICANN
Internet. Is it all that different from what could have been expected of direct
government intervention?
Whether deceptively or naively, official US policy characterized the creation of ICANN as a private-sector driven process that did not affect basic political and
legal rights. It described an act of imposing wholesale centralization and
regulation at the Internet’s core as a way to avoid “government regulation.” The rhetoric of market liberalism was cynically abused to gloss over the true nature of the transition. In short, a fundamental untruth festers at ICANN’s core. The
tumult of ICANN’s first year is the price being paid for that.

###


--------------------------------------------------------------------------
POLITECH -- the moderated mailing list of politics and technology
To subscribe: send a message to majordomo () vorlon mit edu with this text:
subscribe politech
More information is at http://www.well.com/~declan/politech/
--------------------------------------------------------------------------


Current thread: